The Economics of Sport
  • Sports Economics
  • About
  • Workshop
  • Media
  • Selected Publications
  • Book Reviews
  • A Primer on Gaelic Games
  • Upcoming Events
  • Education
  • Resources & Links
  • Data

The Economics of the NFL Draft

29/4/2021

 
By John Considine
Picture
As the NFL draft approached, many commentators appealed to the economics of the draft to explain potential decisions.  A prime example came a few days ago when Mike Tomlin was asked about who makes the decisions in the Pittsburgh draft room.  Tomlin said “At the end of the day, Art Rooney is the boss.”  Interestingly, many of the same commentators seemed to suggest that the owners leveraged their financial power to make a decision on the player they liked in sporting terms rather than the player as a financial asset.

So, what is the economics of the draft?  A pretty good answer to that question is provided by Joel Maxcy’s chapter in The Economics of the National Football League: The State of the Art.  Published in 2012, the book remains relevant even though some of the sentiments expressed might need to be changed, e.g. in a chapter on attendance there is the pre-pandemic sentence "No one wants to watch a game [on TV] at a partially filled stadium even if they are at home."

Maxcy has three main sections in his chapter: History; Economic Analysis; and, Legal Analysis.  The headings suggest a brighter distinction between the sections than is the case.  He could easily have worked the word “economic” into the other headings.  The history section provides a concise account of how interaction between interested parties shaped the development of the NFL.  Between owners of weaker and stronger teams.  Between college and professional organisations.  Between alternative professional leagues.  Between owners and players.  The latter also shows up in the Legal Analysis section where the existence of a Collective Bargaining Agreement has possibly saved the NFL in some antitrust cases.
 
The full title of Maxcy’s chapter is “Economics of the NFL Player Entry Draft System”.  In the economics analysis section, there is some emphasis on the impact of the entry system on salaries.  Maxcy documents some of the increase in salaries that occurred when there was an alternative league.  Another part of the economic analysis section is devoted to the alternative evidence on the competitive balance impact of the draft.  And, there is also a discussion of possible biases in the draft, e.g. those in favour of major colleges and those against black players.
 
Although published almost a decade ago, Maxcy’s chapter remains a nice account of the economics of the NFL draft.  In that decade (sport) economic analysis has further shifted towards empirical analysis of larger data sets.  However, the history and legal sections of this chapter shows that analysis of individual, non-repeating, events can be significant.  Because many of these can be difficult to measure and count, it could mean that their economic, as well as their statistical, significance is lost.  Including a dummy variable for an owner is a less than ideal solution.

Better to Have Loved and Lost

28/4/2021

 
By David Butler

Watching the Leicester vs. Crystal Palace match Monday night I was struck by Leicester’s resilience and, perhaps, what they have learned from last season. I was also thinking about why they are exciting to watch. It seemed that they could often turn matches around. 

As a football supporter, this is where the heartache often lies for me. Yes, losing a match late on is stinging. But losing a match from a winning position brings a certain type of psychological pain – maybe there’s some loss aversion going on.

The table below shows the data for EPL clubs over the last two seasons on this topic. The ‘for’ column shows the number of times a club won from a losing position and the ‘against’ column shows the number of times clubs lost from a winning position.  It is sorted by ‘against’ (decreasing) and then by ‘for’ (increasing). This might give us some insight as to which fans have it hardest.

Spare a thought for Aston Villa fans and those who follow the Saints. Over this season and last, they have lost from winning positions 8 times. Villa fans have only seen their team turn it around 3 times.

Manchester United fans should be very happy. They have regularly shown great resilience, coming from behind (especially away from home) and have only suffered a turnaround once - against Tottenham at home this season.

Some clubs feature quite low on the list a) because they may be not even good enough to get ahead in the first place and b) because they are too good to go behind.

My intuition was right - Leicester are joint top for turning matches around, along with Liverpool.

I'll follow up on this soon and looked at how the psychological pain might be ramped up by losing from a winning position late on.
Picture

Excess Home Wins

23/4/2021

 
By John Considine
From early on in the pandemic, researchers have been estimating the deaths caused by the virus (now with many variants identified by geographical origin).  The most basic calculation is where current deaths are compared with the average for a previous period or periods.  Any excess is attributed to the virus.  We can take a similar approach to examine the excess number of home wins associated with the presence of fans.

As of today there have been 320 games completed of the 380 games in the 2020-21 Premier League season.  There are slightly more away wins (125) than home wins (120).  They are within 5% of each other.  What makes this surprising is that it is well below what normally happens.  If we take the 5 seasons from 2014-15 to 2018-19 then we find that home wins are 51% higher than away wins.  Following basic estimation of excess deaths, we can attribute the excess of home wins over away wins to the presence of fans.  Basic, but a good first approximation.

Below is the ratio of home wins to away wins (no draw/ties included) for this season and five of the previous six seasons.  The 2019-20 season is excluded.
Picture
The above drop in 2020-21 is not a surprise to the readers of the Journal of Sports Economics.  Last May I drew attention to a 2018 paper by Michela Ponzo and Vincenzo Scoppa that addressed the crowds issue using a wonderful set of same city derbies (here).

Elite Clubs and International Demand

22/4/2021

 
By David Butler

The European Super League (ESL) was a short-lived concept. One question that has been asked a lot over the week was why certain clubs were included?  A primary reason is that these clubs are in demand internationally.  

One way of gaining insight to international demand is to consider elite clubs in their off-season.  Increasingly, the founding ESL members have developed elaborate pre/post season tours in locations such as China, North America and Australia. Gone are the days of a pre-season tour in Ireland to limber up for the season ahead. These are now brand building exercises. 

Although tour fixtures are widely perceived as meaningless friendlies, in the sense that no championship points or highly-regarded honours are at stake, big European clubs continue to attract significant turnouts. Over the years attempts have been made to make pre-season friendlies more competitive (e.g. International Champions Cup) but on the surface, international fans appear to resonate to the stars coming to town rather than outcome uncertainty. 

I think the powers that be really cracked it when they realised they must export the European fixture. While the international fan likes to see their home club take on a giant of the sport, attending a Champions League level fixture is really appealing. For example, the Michigan stadium hosted Manchester United vs. Real Madrid in 2014, Chelsea vs. Real Madrid in 2016 and Liverpool vs. Manchester United in 2018; each fixture took place in front of over 100,000 spectators. This is happening for a while now. Over a decade ago Chelsea took on Inter Milan in the Rose Bowl in front of circa 80,000 fans.  

I have attendance data on 241 (non-European) international fixtures for fourteen major European clubs who regularly go on tour outside of Europe. The fixtures took place across thirteen countries, in over one hundred stadia between 2009 and 2019. The table below displays two descriptive statistics by club. Note these averages do not control for the type of opposition (local vs European competitor). Barcelona and Real Madrid top the list for highest average turnout. Many of the 12  ESL founders feature. The maximum attendances give some insight of the appeal of even inconsequential matches internationally. 
Picture

A European Super League?

19/4/2021

 
By Robbie Butler

In the context of European sports, one of the defining characteristics that generally makes it stand out from American sports is the "open" nature of competition. This is more simply known as promotion and relegation. European football, rugby, cricket, and other fields sports punish weaker teams at the end of each season and force them to play in lower tiers of competition.

This is not true of sport in much of the United States. The systems are closed. The NFL, MBL, NBA and even domestic soccer's MLS, all have no relegation mechanism. The opposite occurs in fact. The weakest teams get earlier draft picks, meaning that US sports are typically more balanced than the laissez faire European leagues. The US leagues are generally controlled and managed by the owners of the franchises. In Europe, the clubs are almost always answerable to a different and 'independent' body that administers the competitions they compete in.

In 1888 the Football League was founded. It was in essence a break-away but up to that point fixtures were generally arbitrary. The twelve founding members competed until January 1889. The 4 bottom teams were not relegated but the concept was there - all 4 successfully sought to be re-elected to the league. Therefore, the idea of relegation has been within the Football League - the first football league anywhere in the world - since it's inception. 

In 1992 another break-away league started in England - The Premier League. This was an innovation inspired by sports across the Atlantic. There was opposition at the time to the creation of the Premier League. The movement of all games to subscription television was one of the most contentious issues. 30 years on this decision has revolutionised the game. It has turned small English cities and towns into globally recognised places. Stoke, Burnley, Norwich, Bournemouth, Brighton. The list goes on. 

The announcement of the next break-away league involving English clubs - the European Super League - is nothing new. There are however a number of key difference between this and both 1888 and 1992.

The first is the competition structure and removal of relegation. Such a move would be an Americanisation of European football and a major departure from the accepted norm.

The second is the step outside the national boundary. While European competition has existed since the 1950s, qualification to this was through the domestic leagues. The new Super League would eliminate the need for this. 

The third strikes at the monopsony power of UEFA. While a monopoly is a single seller of a product (something many of us are familiar with) monopsony is a single buyer. As a result the monopsony essentially controls the market as it is the sole purchaser of the goods or services that potential sellers wish to bring to market. This market power can be wielded in order to control the market.

While the major US sports such as NFL, MBL and NBA are better examples of monopsony power, UEFA holds this in a European context. Should one wish to play professional football or operate a football club, UEFA is the sole buyer of this service. It therefore holds monopsony power over the market for European football.

A European Super League would end this, and create a new dynamic in the market. The clubs would be self-governed within this new league and would make the structure resemble something much closer to the American model rather than the European system.

UEFA are not lying down. A ban on playing in all UEFA and FIFA competitions (e.g. the FIFA World Cup) is now the penalty for playing in the new Super League. 

This has a long way to run. Supporters are notoriously conservative when it comes to changing aspects of the game that have deep historical roots. Even largely superficial changes to colours or names have been vigorously rejected by supporters. Moving location - another regular happening in the US - is met with fierce opposition in Europe. Completely upending between 60 and 130 years of competition structure (depending on where you want to draw the line) will be far from straightforward, if even possible at all.

The Return of Golf and The Golf Economy

16/4/2021

 
By John Considine
A recent paper in the BMJ Open Sport and Exercise Medicine gathers a range of evidence that seems to confirm the obvious - the risk of Covid-19 transmission in golf is low.  It is hard to imagine a sport more suited to our current circumstances.  It is a non-contact sport. It is played outdoors on 5km-7km greenways.  At most 150 players are spread across this distance.  Individuals are socially distanced at ranges from the arc of the golf swing to the flight of the golf ball.  In many cases, the only shared equipment are flag sticks and bunker rakes (although the latter have been removed in many cases).  Even here the risks are low according to the BMJ paper.  The authors (Robinson, Foster, and Murray) cite other work that showed "only 0.74% of COVID-19 virus was recoverable at 1 min in high inoculum when applied to a variety of sports equipment (including a golf ball)".

There should be few problems with reopening the sport but the wider golf economy may take a while longer to recover.  Estimates of consumption expenditure on golf were produced a couple of years ago in a commissioned report.  Some are reproduced in Table 4.1 below.  Many of the items that contribute to the overall total continue to suffer due to the pandemic.  The €46m generated from "Food and Beverages" is unlikely to return to these levels anytime soon.  A similar point could be made about the fourth, fifth, and sixth items in Table 4.1.  These will be hit by the problems associated with international travel.
Picture
It is worth drilling down into the €38m figure for Green Fees.  It seems pretty low when you consider that there is approximately 400 golf course on the island of Ireland.   With a green fee of €50 it approximates to about 6 rounds per course per day.  Not a lot.  It leaves plenty of tee-times for the members.  However, that is not the full story.  The distribution of revenues from Green Fees is skewed towards some of the more iconic courses.  A prime example is Lahinch.  It held the Irish Open in 2019 when Jon Rahm proved best of the bunch.  It was expecting revenues of approximately €2m in 2020.  Other courses that have held the Irish Open and Ryder Cup are also favourites of the golfing tourists.  They were expecting Green Fee revenues measured in the millions.  A small number of these courses capture a large proportion of the €38m in Green Fees.  Much of it from international tourists.

Many of these iconic courses have associated accommodation.  The €37m figure for Accommodation in Table 4.1 will not accrue in 2021.  Only when international travel returns to something like normal will these revenues be recovered.  In the short-term even the Irish are not free to play whatever course they wish due to national travel restrictions.  It is a tough time for a sport that poses a small Covid-19 health risk.

Drawing the Line

14/4/2021

 
Picture
By David Butler

It’s hard to be a fan of VAR with its many quirks. At times it is as if the lines are drawn with MS paint.

As fans and pundits rage online on a weekly basis over VAR calls, one part of me does have sympathy for those administrating VAR. Our eyes can deceive us. When we think a player is onside, in fact they may not be. Visual illusions are a mainstay of introductions to behavioural economics – they usually set things up nicely for discussing information-based biases – it follows that if you can’t trust your eyes what else can’t you trust?  

Unsurprisingly, Daniel Kahenman offers a nice insight in Thinking Fast and Slow when discussing the famous Müller-Lyer illusion inset.

“You know that the lines are equally long. If asked about their length, you will say what you know. But you still see the [middle] line as longer. You have chosen to believe the measurement, but you cannot prevent System 1 from doing its thing; you cannot decide to see the lines as equal, although you know they are. To resist the illusion, there is only one thing you can do: you must learn to mistrust your impressions of the length of lines when fins are attached to them. To implement that rule, you must be able to recognize the illusory pattern and recall what you know about it. If you can do this, you will never again be fooled by the Müller-Lyer illusion. But you will still see one line as longer than the other.”

​Is it time to start trusting the technology? As we are often reminded on TV, us viewers only see one angle. Or at least, should we start recognising that our perceptions might be fallible?  

Accepting our intuition failures might be easy for the Müller-Lyer paradox, but this is harder for sport. Fans have clear allegiances and are emotionally engaged. System 2 has to work even harder! 

2000+ Days And Counting

12/4/2021

 
By Robbie Butler

Almost 5 years about I wrote a piece on this blog called "The Difficult Job of Management". The piece plotted the relationship through time between the appointment of each Premier League manager (more than 240 different men) and the number of days in charge.

From 2006 to 2016 the average length of stay for a Premier League manager was just over 400 days. Two weeks ago Liverpool's Jurgen Klopp broke the 2,000-days barrier. One year earlier, now departed Spurs manager Mauricio Pochettino, just about managed the same feat only to be sacked on day 2,002. Both managers, particularly Klopp who could reach 3,000 days in charge (maybe further), very much buck the trend today. One has to go back to 2006 (Mick McCarthy at Wolves) to find a manager than lasted 2,000 or more days since appointment.

And despite, regular periods where his appointment has been question, Ole Gunnar Solskjær is now just 84 days shy of Jose Mourinho's 927 days at Manchester United. Should he reach 928 days, he will be the longest serving United manager since Sir Alex. I think all would agree the chances of Ole reaching Sir Alex's 9,704 days in charge are effectively zero. The game has changed too much since 1986.

And speaking of 1986, and Sir Alex's appointment, the Scot went 1,288 days from his appointment as United manager to the FA Cup replay win over Crystal Palace at Wembley in May 1990. Should United not win the Europa League this season, Ole will be in Ferguson territory (1000+ days) as he searches for his first piece of silverware. Quite remarkable in today's game when most managers get 400 days or less.

The Evolution of the Football Jersey - An Institutional Perspective

6/4/2021

 
"By Robbie Butler

We were delighted to learn last week of the acceptance of our paper "The Evolution of the Football Jersey - An Institutional Perspective" in the Journal of Institutional Economics. 

This paper explores the interaction of informal constraints on human behaviour by examining the evolution of English football jerseys. The jersey provides an excellent setting to demonstrate how informal constraints emerge from formal rules and shape human behaviour. Customs, approved norms and habits are all observed in this setting.

The commercialisation of football in recent decades has resulted in these informal constraints, in many cases dating back over a century, co-existing with branding, goodwill and identity effects. Combined these motivate clubs to maintain the status quo. As a result, club colours have remained remarkably resilient within a frequently changing landscape.

​The paper is currently going through the production process but should be available online in the coming weeks, and will appear later in the year in the journal.

Tom Brady, NFL, and Decision Making

2/4/2021

 
By John Considine
Picture
Richard Thaler devotes Chapter 29 of Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioral Economics to (American) Football.  Most of the chapter is devoted to illustrating how early round draft picks subsequently underperform and/or are overcompensated.  Thaler is also critical of giving away future draft picks.  It is part of Thaler’s case against presumptions about the efficiency of decision making.
 
I was reminded of Thaler’s work by developments in recent weeks.  The trade that exchanged Jared Goff for Matthew Stafford involved the Rams giving up draft picks.  Does this illustrate the benefits from trade or the pull of instant gratification?  It should be noted that some commentators suggest that giving up first round draft picks can help teams avoid criticism like the Bears got for their drafting of Mitchell Trubisky before Patrick Mahomes and Deshaun Watson.
 
Thaler’s work draws attention to decision making errors.  One could argue that he was forced to over emphasise this aspect to get a hearing in economics where the default is to assume that human decision making is correct (or self-correcting).  Again, recent developments are worth considering.  Dak Prescott’s new deal with the Cowboys can be interpreted in a variety of ways.  Some suggest he is now being overcompensated because he was undercompensated previously.  A sort of market correction.  Others suggest that Jerry Jones made an error by not doing a deal with Dak earlier.
 
Dak himself spun a different story.  Dak saw his new deal as helping other players by raising the bar for all players looking to negotiate a new deal.  He has a point.  But he may damage his team’s ability to hire - especially in a year where the salary cap is coming down.  Some might say that Dak is not making the “rational choice” that Tom Brady has previously made.  In The Importance of Small Decisions Brady’s structuring of his deals in New England was presented as being aligned with the economist’s idea of rational choice (here is a previous blog on this point).  I wonder if that example overplays the success of Brady’s decision making in a way that Thaler may overplay the errors in the draft.

If The Importance of Small Decisions makes it to a second edition then I guess that Brady’s decision to move to Tampa will be included.  Another ring followed that decision.  (How might it view Brady's decision to engage in practice with teammates that possible broke coronavirus restrictions?)

Few economists claim that the rational choice model explains every aspect of decision making.  Most think it is a very useful framework.  If it explained all choices then why would we have to include the "rational" part.  Rational choice was one of four quadrants in The Importance of Small Decisions.  Thaler tends to place it within one of two systems of decision making.  These two systems are roughly captured by the title of a book by Daniel Kahneman - Thinking, Fast and Slow.  These systems are also present in Thaler's co-authored Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness.  In these publications, one system is slow, conscious, and deliberative (not inconsistent with rational choice).  The other system is fast, intuitive, and automatic.  Many decision making errors are attributed to this second system.  Kahneman allows that experts make less of these errors but he is careful to circumscribe the circumstances where this applies (see here).  The default emphasis of Thaler and Kahneman is on the errors in human decision making.

The Importance of Small Decisions uses Tom Brady as the poster boy for rational choice.  I have not come across Kahneman or Thaler using Tom Brady to illustrate to successes of human decision making.  It is hard to imagine.  One of Thaler's favourite characters is Homer Simpson (he complains that rational choice uses characters like Star Trek's Mr Spock).  We need to look outside of economics to find Brady playing a similar role for fast, intuitive, automatic decision making.  In Game Changer: The Art of Sports Science Fergus Connolly takes four pages to describe 2.3 seconds of Tom Brady’s decision making in a Super Bowl.  Four pages for 2.3 seconds.  Connolly is slow and deliberative in describing a decision making process that is fast and instinctive.  Connolly talks about inputs being transformed into actions in “auto pilot mode” and without some of the inputs making it “all the way to his brain”.  An expert decision maker in action.

When it comes to decision making in economics, and in sport, too often we over emphasise either the successes or failures of decision making.  It is the mixture that makes it interesting.

    Archives

    December 2022
    November 2022
    October 2022
    September 2022
    August 2022
    July 2022
    June 2022
    May 2022
    April 2022
    March 2022
    February 2022
    January 2022
    December 2021
    November 2021
    October 2021
    September 2021
    August 2021
    July 2021
    June 2021
    May 2021
    April 2021
    March 2021
    February 2021
    January 2021
    December 2020
    November 2020
    October 2020
    September 2020
    August 2020
    July 2020
    June 2020
    May 2020
    April 2020
    March 2020
    February 2020
    January 2020
    December 2019
    November 2019
    October 2019
    September 2019
    August 2019
    June 2019
    May 2019
    April 2019
    March 2019
    February 2019
    January 2019
    December 2018
    November 2018
    October 2018
    September 2018
    August 2018
    July 2018
    June 2018
    May 2018
    April 2018
    March 2018
    February 2018
    January 2018
    December 2017
    November 2017
    October 2017
    September 2017
    August 2017
    July 2017
    June 2017
    May 2017
    April 2017
    March 2017
    February 2017
    January 2017
    December 2016
    November 2016
    October 2016
    September 2016
    August 2016
    July 2016
    June 2016
    May 2016
    April 2016
    March 2016
    February 2016
    January 2016
    December 2015
    November 2015
    October 2015
    September 2015
    August 2015
    July 2015
    June 2015
    May 2015
    April 2015
    March 2015
    February 2015
    January 2015
    December 2014
    November 2014
    October 2014
    September 2014
    August 2014
    July 2014
    June 2014
    May 2014
    April 2014
    March 2014
    February 2014
    January 2014
    December 2013
    November 2013
    October 2013
    September 2013
    August 2013
    July 2013

    About

    This website was founded in July 2013.

    RSS Feed

    Categories

    All
    American Football
    Athletics
    Baseball
    Basketball
    Behavioural Economics
    Boxing
    Broadcasting
    Competitive Balance
    Cricket
    Cycling
    Darts
    David Butler
    Declan Jordan
    Drugs
    Ed Valentine
    Epl
    Esports
    Expenditure
    F1
    Fifa World Cup
    Finances
    Funding
    Gaa
    Gaelic Games
    Gambling
    Game Theory
    Gary Burns
    Geography
    Golf
    Greyhound Racing
    Guest Posts
    Horse Racing
    Impact Studies
    John Considine
    John Eakins
    League Of Ireland
    Location
    Media
    Mls
    Mma
    Olympics
    Participation
    Paul O'Sullivan
    Premier League
    Regulation
    Research
    Robbie Butler
    Rugby
    Simpsonomics
    Snooker
    Soccer
    Spatial Analysis
    Sporting Bodies
    Stephen Brosnan
    Swimming
    Taxation
    Teaching
    Technology
    Tennis
    Transfers
    Uefa
    Ufc
    World Cup
    Wwe

Related

The website is not formally affiliated to any institution and all of the entries represent the personal views and opinions of an individual contributor. The website operates on a not-for-profit basis. For this reason we decline all advertisement opportunities. 

Contact

To contact us email sportseconomics2013@gmail.com or find us on Twitter @SportEcon.